Search This Blog

Tuesday, December 18, 2018

A Return to Value


A Return to Value

We are currently going through the second market correction this year. The first one occurred in February. This second correction is deeper of course and scarier. Corrections are a healthy part of the market process and they occur largely to clean up the excesses of the previous upswing. The market at its core is no more than a complicated thought form and the energy within it, is made of all the various market participants. When the market goes up strongly people get bullish and feed off of each other’s energy (the fear of missing out on easy money). They will climb over each other in their desire to buy stocks. They will reach and put in a higher bid in their zest to buy and own shares. A premium is put on the future growth potential of companies as people get increasingly bullish about the prospects of the future. When this happens things can get sloppy and overdone on the upside and it reaches a point where everybody who could buy has already bought and a correction ensues to siphon off the excesses of the previous bull run. (see the blogposts about the Speculator's Edge for more insight into the nature of the marketplace.)

But as I mentioned earlier, this is the second correction this year. That is rare and I have a feeling the inner workings of the market are going through a pivotal change in their nature. The market is chameleon-like in its essence and as time goes by it changes and morphs into something it wasn’t before. We have gone through an incredible period since the 2008/2009 financial crisis. The powers that be had to pump an incredible amount of liquidity into the financial system to offset the damage inflicted by the financial crisis. Almost all of that money went into the stock market (especially the U.S. market). But the Fed has had to put themselves in so much debt in creating all this liquidity that they now find themselves forced to siphon it back out of the market.

Couple that fact with the rare occurrence of two market corrections in one year and I think a changing of the guard is occurring in the marketplace. Growth stocks will no longer be given a premium valuation for their earnings potential. As there is less money sloshing around in the system, investors will be more careful in committing their funds to investments. They are liable to become more value orientated. Value investing has under-performed Growth investing since 2008/2009. That is a market anomaly. The reverse is usually true.

Once this correction runs its course I believe investors will be looking out on a new world. One in which value will again regain the investing mantle it has given up to growth over the last decade. People will be more careful with their investment dollars because they will have less of them to invest….The way I see it anyway…





Sunday, December 16, 2018

How to find Investment Ideas with a Margin of Safety


How to find Investment Ideas with a Margin of Safety

As a follow-up to yesterday's post, remember at times of emotional extremes it pays to be contrary. The great irony of the current sell-off is that it presents an investor who can stand aside from the mania of the crowd, an opportunity to buy the stock's of good companies on the cheap. The price you pay for these companies will have a built-in 'margin of safety.' And in the long run that is what the game is largely about.

The best investment opportunities usually come in big waves, such as when the entire market declines. Big sell-offs in the market can cause forced selling. When this happens money managers are forced to sell the stocks in their funds because of client redemptions who panic at all the bad news and just want to liquidate their holdings as fast as they can (the herd effect of the crowd). The fund managers may know that they’re selling under-valued securities but they have no choice. This can create a vicious feedback-loop effect where indiscriminate selling begets more selling, as some stocks will just be dumped for reasons that have nothing to do with the companies underlying fundamentals. Hedge funds that use leverage are even more susceptible to this forced selling as they no longer can make their margin calls and are forced to dump everything so they can raise liquidity. The solitary investor, who can stand aside from the galloping herd of the market, can take advantage of the situation and cherry pick the low hanging fruit the market is offering him.

The beauty of forced sellers is that they have no choice. They have to sell regardless of price. If chaos is widespread, many people will be forced to sell at the same time and few people will be in a position to provide the required liquidity. The difficulties that mandate selling – plummeting prices, withdrawal of credit, fear among counter-parties or clients – have the same impact on most investors. Prices can fall far below their intrinsic value. This can cause an imbalance between the sellers and buyers in the market place. It can be a scary time but an alert investor who puts an emphasis on the importance of his purchase price can buy things at this uncertain time which will have a built in ‘margin of safety’. So ironically at a time of seeming danger and fear an investor with the right disposition can actually do the safest thing in the long run and buy cheap.


Saturday, December 15, 2018

Where there is Uncertainty, there is Opportunity


Where there is Uncertainty, there is Opportunity

An argument is made that there are just too many question marks about the near future; wouldn’t it be better to wait until things clear up a bit? You know the prose: Maintain buying reserves until current uncertainties are resolved,” etc…Before reaching for that crutch, face up to two unpleasant facts: The future is never clear and you pay a very high price for a cheery consensus. Uncertainty actually is the friend of the buyer of long-term values.

Warren Buffet


While most value investors are typically considered a risk-averse lot, that’s more to do with the price they’re willing to pay for a given investment. Often the types of situations that attract them are fraught with uncertainty and are perceived by the crowd as being downright dangerous. As companies constantly evolve and change in response to industry or company-specific challenges and opportunities, the lack of clarity around those changes - and the risks that are entailed in the potential outcomes – can cause share prices to diverge widely from the underlying value of the business. The ability to recognize and take advantage of that dynamic is a key element of what sets the best investors apart from the crowd. There are two kinds of events that create uncertainty (volatility) which can offer the investor who can think for himself, an opportunity to take advantage of the herd-like behaviour of the crowd. 

The first revolve around individual companies, such as earnings misses, unexpected news, M&A activity, restructurings and legal issues – things that can make prices and valuations change relatively quickly. In general, prices change much faster than the fundamentals of businesses change. It is the individual investor’s job to investigate what made the price change and then figure out whether the facts have changed as much as the price, if they haven’t changed that much that can be an opportunity to buy something cheap.

The other major source of uncertainty is when a macro event or trend causes the markets to move. These can be industry – specific, but more often than not it involves interest rate moves, currency moves, political instability, and the overall economic outlook. The market reflects at any moment what the stock market crowd think a business is worth, so if macroeconomic factors force people to buy and sell a companies’ stock  while ignoring the long term fundamentals of the company, this can create a disconnect with the price of its stock and what the underlying company is really worth. This can create an opportunity for the observant self-aware investor who can think for himself, to move in and take advantage of the disconnect between the stock's price and its value.




Friday, December 14, 2018

Know What You Own

Know What You Own

In lieu of the recent sell-off, the DIY investor at home often panics and sells off a lot of his holdings impulsively as the fear in the marketplace gets the better of him. To help protect an investor from himself it’s usually wise to understand the companies he owns and why he bought them in the first place. That in fact might be a better way to achieve a margin of safety than to just blindly diversify his holdings into a lot of companies he doesn’t understand.

The first step in building a margin of safety is to research the company.

There is a plethora of literature available for anyone who is interested in learning how to analyze a company…Read the financial statements. Since the passing of the Safe Harbor Act in 1995, U.S. companies have been incented to provide timely and accurate financial statements in their 10-K, 10-Q, and proxy statements. The 10-K and 10-Q (annual and quarterly reports) each provide three financial statements: income statement, cash flow statement, and balance sheet. There is plenty of information available in these three statements to allow an investor to thoroughly understand how the company operates. The proxy statement discusses management compensation. A brief examination of the proxy statement will offer great insights into how top management compensates itself.

For investors who are seeking a deeper understanding of the company, there are many more questions to pose. Has the company increased its earnings, revenue, and cash flow consistently over the long term? Is it in an industry that has long-term growth potential? Is the management team stable and experienced? Has management laid out its goals and milestones? Has it delivered on those milestones? Has it been successful in expanding its services or its product line? Has the company treated its shareholders fairly?

Recent changes in the disclosure laws plus the ubiquitous Internet have given individual investors the ability to easily access and read transcripts of quarterly management conference calls and corporate presentations to institutional shareholders. These transcripts often give investors valuable clues into the mindset of top management. There is no excuse today for any investor, large or small, to be insufficiently informed on any public company.

Benjamin Graham and the Power of Growth Stocks,
Frederick K. Martin

Tuesday, December 11, 2018

The Financial Media, Market Indexes and the 10 Year Treasury Bill


The Financial Media, Market Indexes and the 10 Year Treasury Bill

If you don't control your own thinking, someone else will control it for you.

Neville Goddard


Price is a function of supply and demand characteristics, which are often influenced by the news of the day and short-term results. This has always been true, but is even more so today with social media, the 24‑hour news cycle and all the information available to investors. Value, on the other hand, is the net present value of future cash flows based on assumptions for growth, discounted at an appropriate interest rate. The Price of a publicly traded security is often not the Value of it. The trading Price is known daily. Value takes knowledge and experience to fully define, and is more often an art than an exact science.

Bruce Flatt, CEO of Brookfield Asset Management


You encounter life with your attention. Attention is awareness, mindfulness, and watchful consciousness. When millions of people focus their attention upon listening to the same words, seeing the same pictures, and hearing the same descriptions, tremendous energy is generated and a massive thought-form is created (many bodies sustaining the same belief.)

The financial media wants to capture your attention so they can expand their viewing audience and in doing so, attract the attention of advertisers who will in turn pay them for the privilege of obtaining access to that viewing audience. In this way the advertisers and the media both make money…at your expense.

The media captures your attention by preying on your worst fears by manipulating you into believing something that at its core is not true. The following illustrates two examples of misinformation involving interpreting market behaviour and interest rates.

Market Indexes do not represent the market. Many of them are capitalization weighted meaning that a handful of huge companies can move the whole index all by themselves. A much better barometer of the health of the overall market is the momentum of market breadth. Momentum of the market breadth bottomed in late October and is currently higher now than it was then. In other words the worst is over and its now time to go shopping the same way one would when the supermarket is running a sale, only in this case many of the stocks of public companies are for sale.

The last couple of months the media have been sounding the alarm of rising interest rates, indicating that it is bad for the return of stocks going forward. The risk free rate I watch is the yield on the 10 Year Bill. When you get a chance go on the net and take a look at a long term chart of the yield of the 10 Year Bill. You will be shocked how low it is relative to its history. In other words the discount rate for a company’s future cash flows is still very accommodative

Sunday, December 9, 2018

David Driscoll is a Smart Guy…But


David Driscoll is a Smart Guy…But

I think you have to find the right approach to investing that fits into your own psychological makeup. One size may be a good fit for a lot of people, but not for everybody. I write this blog for DIY (do-it-yourself) investors at home, but I really write it for myself. I’ve always been unconventional and prefer to go my own way. I’ve read a lot about the markets both before I started to invest and after. It’s a passion for me and I find it endlessly fascinating. The markets are a dynamic, multifaceted, sometimes contradictory phenomenon that is constantly in motion and changing its shape. What follows are some basic truths I’ve come to believe in at this point in my investing life.

I believe in buying and holding positions for long periods of time. I believe in running a concentrated portfolio where you know what you own on a fundamental basis. Volatility is not risk, its noise and if you invest for the long term you can safely ignore it. Permanenetly losing money is the risk I'm concerned about. Volatility is something I believe you have to embrace as a long-term investor. It is not something to avoid (that is how most people think.) People are frightened by volatility because they are not familiar enough with what they own in their portfolio. Accept volatility and concentration. To me diversification is the bane of performance. Know what you own and why you own it. I haven’t always followed this rule and when I haven’t I have regretted it.

Running a portfolio is a solitary activity. Don’t discuss it with other people. They will only impose their own biased opinions on you and create doubt in your mind. I prefer to make my own mistakes. I can live with that. And when I do make a mistake, I try to learn from it. Leave your decision making uncontaminated and develop your own sources of information.

I’ve developed a knowledge base that has deepened and widened over time…and as it has evolved my intuitive powers have heightened and have come more and more into play. Maybe some news item might trigger a thought process that develops into an investment opportunity. Investing is more of an art form, not a science. Leave the quants and propeller-heads with their algorithms and spreadsheets...along with their under-performance.

I’ve learned to exploit the edges I think I have over my competition; both informational (utilizing  underused information) and emotional (knowing and observing my own behavior under emotional extremes).

Maybe most important of all, I try to be different because I am different. We all have hidden resources within ourselves which we can utilize once we get out of the ‘victim’ mentality...Every individual investor has to find his own truth.







Saturday, December 8, 2018

David Driscoll on BNN-Bloomberg’s Market Call – Dec 07, 2018


David Driscoll on BNN-Bloomberg’s Market Call – Dec 07, 2018

David Driscoll both educates as well as invests in the markets. I don't always agree with what he says but he is always worth listening too. the following piece lays out a good part of his investing philosophy.

MARKET OUTLOOK

Given the sharp drop in equity markets since Oct. 1, it’s certainly a wonderful thing to be holding 20 per cent cash multiplied by the equity weight in clients’ portfolios. Despite not being fully invested, our client equity holdings are up this year while the market is down. The difference is what’s known as “alpha.” If an investor is up five per cent and the market is down five per cent, then the alpha is 10 per cent. That’s the way to evaluate a portfolio manager. If their alpha is consistently greater than two per cent or more each year after fees, you’ve got a good portfolio manager.

The reasons behind our positive alpha are:
 1) The stocks in our portfolios are companies that generate consistently rising free cash flows. They have the financial flexibility to deal with whatever the macroeconomic environment (slower growth) or politicians (tariffs, trade wars) throw at them. As a result, we have no need to trade these stocks and then incur transaction costs and capital gains tax. Instead, the clients can keep the nickels and dimes for themselves while never missing out on a dividend payment. Remember: two thirds of all performance comes from rising dividends and the re-investment of those dividends, not stock price movement.
2) We have a fully diversified, global portfolio (both stocks and bonds) with no correlation risk. Each of the 30 stocks in the portfolio is out there in the world doing its own thing and not competing directly with other stocks. We own one Canadian bank (TD), not all six of them. Since the Canadian banks’ price performances have all been negative in 2018, we’re not suffering from their underperformance.
3) We currently hold 20 per cent cash times the equity weight in the portfolio. For example, if the asset mix is 60 per cent stocks and 40 per cent fixed income, the cash holding is 20 per cent times 60 per cent, which equals 12 per cent cash. If it’s an all-equity portfolio, the cash weight is 20 per cent. Cash is known as a “synthetic short,” meaning if you’re 80 per cent in stocks and 20 per cent in cash, your equity exposure is only 60 per cent (80 per cent minus 20 per cent) and you won’t go down with the market unlike investors in index funds or ETFs, who are suffering the full brunt of this current equity sell-off.
4) Our portfolios all have a weighted average portfolio beta of less than one. This means less volatility relative to the market. If an investor had a portfolio of only semiconductor stocks whose betas are around 1.50, their performance would be 50 per cent worse than the market indexes. For example, if the market was down 10 per cent, they’d be down 15 per cent.
5) The dividend growth among the Liberty global stocks has averaged 15 per cent in 2018: about double the historical average of all publicly-listed stocks worldwide. This helps the portfolios to provide both income and growth. The faster the income grows, the greater the downside protection it provides. This is because that dividend income is guaranteed and provides cash for future purchases in a down market at cheaper prices.
6) Our bond portfolios are laddered. Think of each rung of a ladder as a year in which a bond matures. If a bond matures each year from 2019 to 2029 and interest rates rise, there’ll always be a bond maturing that can be rolled over into a higher coupon instrument. This is known as bond immunization. Think of it as an annual flu shot against rising rates.
7) If you own fixed income it’s important to own some inflation-protected bonds. For our clients, we have five per cent of the portfolio allocated to these types of bonds. They’re the only instruments that protect you from inflation on the fixed income side of your portfolio. If you own the Canadian three per cent real return bond (RRB) due in 2036, the coupon is three per cent plus the inflation rate (currently 2.4 per cent in Canada), for a total payout of 5.4 per cent for 2018. Given the current inflation rate, investors in short-term bonds or GICs are earning a “real return” (after tax and inflation) that is negative; that means their spending power is declining, not rising.
8) Being invested in international securities (stocks and bonds) gives you protection against a drop in the Canadian dollar (currently down about five per cent this year against the U.S. dollar). While some may say they don’t want to be invested in European markets or emerging markets, it’s an imprudent comment. Year-to-date, our European stocks are up three per cent while the comparable benchmark is down 11 per cent and our investment in Jardine Matheson,  a company with subsidiaries in Southeast Asia, is up 10 per cent against the Asia-Pacific indexes, which are down anywhere from four per cent (Japan) to 21 per cent (China).
If you own a fully diversified global portfolio, then you have nothing to worry about regardless of what’s happening in the stock markets today.


Wednesday, December 5, 2018

Price versus Value


Price versus Value

Price is a function of supply and demand characteristics, which are often influenced by the news of the day and short-term results. This has always been true, but is even more so today with social media, the 24‑hour news cycle and all the information available to investors. Value, on the other hand, is the net present value of future cash flows based on assumptions for growth, discounted at an appropriate interest rate. The Price of a publicly traded security is often not the Value of it. The trading Price is known daily. Value takes knowledge and experience to fully define, and is more often an art than an exact science.

Bruce Flatt, CEO of Brookfield Asset Management


Read the above very carefully. When the markets go down sharply as they did yesterday, it is a time to buy stocks, not sell them. Avoid getting emotional and stay rational. It’s the only way. At times of emotional extremes, be contrary. Tune out the mindless media who are more interested in attracting advertising revenue by selling fear and catering to the worst instincts of the retail investor. Read Howard Marks or the public disclosures of great CEO’s like Bruce Flatt. Remember why you bought your holdings in the first place. The short-term price movement of a security is as fickle as the attention span of a goldfish. Now is the time to buy quality at a discount price. The chances of doing that now are much greater than they were two or three months ago. Think long term and be aggressive while others are running for the exits. And if you have little money to invest right now, just hold. Six months from now, you’ll be glad you did...Demand Supply...


Monday, December 3, 2018

Stephen Takacsy on BNN-Bloomberg’s Market Call – Dec 03,2018

Stephen Takacsy on BNN-Bloomberg’s Market Call – Dec 03,2018

MARKET OUTLOOK:

Over the past few months, we finally saw a massive sell-off in stock markets led by the U.S, which we believe is a healthy and long overdue correction. The U.S stock market was disconnected from the rest of the world (which was already struggling), with rich valuations led by a small group of tech stocks, and an escalating U.S-China trade war to start which were going to start having an impact on corporate earnings. There were also increasing financial risks from rising interest rates, potential wage inflation from a tight labour market and higher cost imports subject to Trump’s tariffs. Also, there were other signs of a market top as evidenced by various speculative manias such as cannabis stocks and cryptocurrencies which have been crashing in value.

However, the sell-off was magnified by algorithmic trading, momentum and quant funds selling, and retail panic selling from margin calls and ETFs. This explains a lot of the volatility we've have been seeing on an intraday basis. Also, the Canadian stock market has been suffering from institutional outflows due to our energy sector challenges. We’ve seen indiscriminate liquidation exasperated by current tax loss selling which has created huge opportunities, particularly in the small and mid-cap sectors. There are many great companies trading at historic low valuations despite record results and strong prospects. Also, some higher-yielding dividend stocks and preferred shares have dropped to very attractive levels as a result of the rise in interest rates.

TOP PICKS:

CENTRIC HEALTH (CHH.TO)
Last buy around $0.25

Centric is one of Canada’s largest specialty pharma providers of medication and healthcare services to senior residences serving 31,000 beds. A new CEO from Cardinal Health was recently hired to improve profits at the pharma business which was recently impacted by drug price reforms in Ontario and Alberta and its sale of non-core assets to pay down debt. Centric also announced an agreement with Canopy Growth to supply medical cannabis to senior communities and is launching a revolutionary automated drug delivery device for seniors living at home called Karie. The company is one of the best bargains on the TSX. Once the surgery clinics are sold in the next few months and the pharma profits start to increase, the stock could easily double. The technology investment in Karie alone could be worth more than Cnetric’s entire market cap which gives it additional upside. The stock is trading at under six times earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBITDA) pro-forma asset sales.

VELAN (VLN.TO)
Last buy around $9.00

Valen is an Industrial valve manufacturer is based in Montreal and is the world leader in nuclear valves. After a few down years, backlog has been growing and management is focused on improving margins through production efficiencies and selling higher value added products. Velan is a classic value investment trading at a massive discount to tangible net book value. The strock trades at $9 versus a tangibale net book of $17 and has $3 per share in cash. We don’t think the company should remain public. Instead, it should be sold to a large multinational player in order to be competitive on a global scale. If Velan were to be sol to a larger stategic player,  the stock should be worht $20. 

NFI GROUP (NFI.TO 1.16%)
Last buy around $38.00

NFI Group is one of three major manufacturers of transit buses and motor coaches in North America. The stock is down nearly 40 per cent in the past few months and yet it released record profits. While growth has slowed from acquisitions and the multiple has contracted, backlog is strong and margins are steady with little impact from tariffs. NFI is also a leader in electric buses. This recession proof business is trading at under 10 times earnings. It also has a 4 per cent dividend yield. We expect this company to continue growing its earnings per share and the stock to move back into the $50s.

Stephen Takacsy, Lester Asset Mangement



Tuesday, November 27, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Ten


The Speculator’s Edge, Ten


How Speculators get Paid

Congratulation! You now know all you need to know to begin to approach the markets as a speculator. You understand what the markets are and how they function. Most importantly, you understand that to win you must do your job as a speculator and you know exactly what that job is. The rest should be easy, right?

Wrong…

Most economists understand the theory of speculation and yet are unable to profit as speculators. Why should this be so?

Because the market is comprised of some pretty smart people with a lot of money who are trying to do exactly the same thing you are. These people are your competition. Their competition makes the markets pretty darn efficient (hard to beat).

Because it is human nature and the nature of the markets that even if you know what you’re supposed to do, you won’t want to do what you have to do when the opportunity arises. You won’t want to buy when things are bleakest, when blood is in the streets – yet this is precisely the time when there is the most supply for speculators to demand. You won’t want to sell when things are brightest either – but that is when demand is as high as it’s ever going to get and your job is to supply it.

Because the markets are a social process, they can do anything at any time.

And because, even when you think you have it all figured out, from time to time it is likely that you are going to be blindsided by some totally unforeseeable event that drastically disrupts or alters the whole valuation process.

Having said all that, it is possible, rewarding, challenging, and imperative for those who are able and willing to preserve their capital and endeavour to grow. It requires knowledge, the ability to observe, and the ability to act on what you know and observe. And, by the way, it can be incredibly fun – as long as you remember not to let its entertainment value deter you from your purpose.

Most people approach the market by attempting to forecast prices, instead of recognizing current or forecasting future conditions of supply and demand. Since we know better, we should approach any other tool we come across (technical analysis, fundamental analysis, contrary opinion etc) to determine their utility in helping us demand supply and supply demand – that is, helping us do our jobs as speculators.

The Speculator’s Edge
Albert Peter Pacelli

Monday, November 26, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Nine


The Speculator’s Edge, Nine


How Speculators get Paid

So far we have learned…

1) The pricing process is a social process. Prices are the results of subjective valuations of individual members of society and are subject to change at their whim. Ludwig von Mises, an economist of the conservative Austrian school put it this way:

“But supply and demand are only the links in a chain of phenomena, one end of which has this visible manifestation in the market, while the other is anchored deep in the human mind.”

The process is not scientific. It is not mathematical. It is not mystical or astrological. On an individual level it is psychological. On a mass level it is social.

2) All known prices are historical facts. The notion of current market prices is fictional. Prices are neither current nor of the market. Trades that have occurred are historical facts. They occur only between individuals.

3) There is no such thing as fair value. Value is in the eye of the beholder. In fact, the law of marginal utility tells us that the value of a good varies even on an individual level, depending on how much of it the individual already has. When a trade occurs, it occurs because the parties to the trade disagree as to the utility of the good traded. For the trade to have occurred, it must have been subjectively viewed as advantageous to each party.

4) All prices are independent of one another. Each valuation is an individual valuation. It is subject to change at no notice and for no reason. In assessing an uncertain future, a person may use only experience and reason. Admittedly, past prices are a part of man’s experience and as such must play a part in his or her thinking about the future. But it is the anticipation of future conditions that determines current valuations, not past prices.

5) The supply and demand curves are fictional descriptions that never occur. That ceteris paribus (all things being equal) greater supply would exist at higher prices is a rational conclusion. But ceteris are never paribus (non-price determinants never are the same).

6) While ultimately price depends on current utility to consumers, at any given moment it reflects speculative assessment of future utility. Consumers determine price. But, it is not merely current consumption that determines price; it is the anticipated consumption as well.

7) The people doing the anticipating are speculators. Speculators act as conduits between producers and consumers assuming unwanted risks of production and rationing supply among consumers so as to maximize utility.

The Speculator's Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli


Sunday, November 25, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Eight


The Speculator’s Edge, Eight


Why Speculators get Paid

Speculators only get paid if they do their job. The answer to how and why speculators get paid is found in basic textbook economics.

In Economics, Samuelson and Nordhaus identify three dimensions in which speculators “link up markets”: over time, over space, and over risks.

Markets separated by distance may have different prevailing prices for identical goods. If the difference between prices exceeds the costs associated with transportation, speculators will buy the goods in the market offering the lower price and sell in the market bidding the higher price, realizing the difference in the two prices. Since the goods must be transported to the place of sale, costs of shipping must be subtracted from the trading profit. The activity of the speculators is called arbitrage. As the arbitrage continues, prices will tend to fall in the market having the higher price (because of speculative buying). By arbitraging the two markets, speculators cause goods to move from the lower priced market to the higher priced market, until the prices of the two markets come into line. The movement of goods from the lower priced market to the higher priced market is economically optimum, since the higher price reflects higher demand or lower supply. The important point is that speculative profit resulted only from performing an economic service. If the speculators were not conferring a benefit on the system, they would not be rewarded for their activity.

The second category of speculative activity occurs across time…Assume that the consumer’s utility schedule for cotton is constant over two years. (In other words, the demand for cotton is the same in both periods.) In the first year, there is an unusually large crop of cotton, say five pounds per person, and in the second year, a small crop of only three pounds per person. In year one, since the crop is big, the price will fall to low levels. Low price levels will encourage consumption of the cotton by marginal consumers, consumers who would not otherwise use the cotton in year one except for its low price. In year two, the small crop comes in and prices soar. Now only those consumers who desire the cotton badly enough to pay the high price will consume it. What has happened is that marginal consumers in year one displaced higher order consumers in year two. As a result, total utility over the two-year period was not maximized.

We can go a step further and show that if the circumstances of the bumper crop in year one and the shortage in year two could have been forseen, then the total utility for the two years would be maximized only if the consumption was equal in both years. This results from the fact that the consumer’s utility schedule is the same in both years.

Note that there are several key words in the preceding paragraph: :if the circumstances…could have been for seen.” Speculators make a living out of forseeing things. In the example, astute speculators who recognized the unusually large nature of the crop in year one might very well decide to take some cotton into inventory, figuring that higher prices would prevail the following year either because the low prices of year one would discourage cotton growers from planting so much or simply because the odds favour some bad weather sooner or later. The speculative activity in year one would tend to support the price of cotton, preventing marginal consumption. Then, in year two, there would be enough cotton to go around, as speculators made up the shortfall in supply be selling cotton from their inventories… Once again, you can see that speculators providing a service get paid for doing so.

The third important category of speculative services is the absorbtion of risk…Imagine that you own a copper mine that produces 100,000 pounds of copper per year. Your production costs amount to $.60 per pound. You are operating your mine with the expectation that the price of copper will be $.75 per pound. But, alas, we live in a risky world. Prices might go as low as $.50 per pound or as high as $1.00. At the low end, you will lose $10,000 per year. At the high end, you will make $40,000. If you are like most rational business persons, you would much prefer a sure sale of your production at $.75 cents per pound, which will yield your anticipated profit of $25,000…Why?

There are two reasons. First, since copper mining is your principle means of income, to the extent possible, you prefer to run it on as certain a basis as possible. What happens if you get unlucky for a couple of years? You are wiped out of your means of making a living. If you wish to assume a high degree of risk, you will do it with capital that you have specifically earmarked for that purpose.

The second reason is that the marginal utility of the windfall profits you might earn if copper goes to $1.00 per pound is less than the marginal disutility if copper declines to $.50 per pound. In other words, the added income means less, perhaps since it only enables you to buy better clothes, than the loss of income, since it might preclude you from buying clothes altogether.

So, we conclude you are risk-averse. You would jump at the opportunity to sell your next year’s production of copper to some speculator right now for $.75 even though prices might be higher later. You might even sell it for $.72 or a little less – after all, you can’t expect some speculator to do you such a big favour unless you pay him a little something for taking the risk. We call what you pay him a risk premium.

Again, you can see that speculators get paid for performing a valuable economic service, in this case, assuming from producers unwanted risks of fluctuating prices. And we can go one step further and say that the greater the risk assumed by a speculator, the greater the potential rewards that he or she can reap.

Economists say that speculators get paid for reducing variations in consumption and for assuming unwanted risks of ownership. I say that speculators get paid for demanding supply and supplying demand. Used in context, we mean the same thing. My terminology is employed for a simple reason: It reminds me in a practical way of what I must do as a speculator to win. In all the previous examples, in each case, successful speculators as a class were purchasing from producers, taking goods into inventory, and supplying them to consumers as a class. The words, “demanding supply and supplying demand” help remind me to do this.

No matter how you say it, this is the key to the whole business of speculation. Your job is to increase the utility of the economy by seeing that the people who want things most get them. If you do your job as a speculator, you will be amply rewarded. If you don’t, you won’t

You might also note that speculators who misread economic circumstances are guilty of performing a disservice. By selling when they should be buying and vice versa, they increase dislocations and risk. Fortunately, the markets have a way of dealing with these people: by summarily taking their capital away and giving it to the speculators who are doing their job.

The Speculator’s Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli












Saturday, November 24, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Seven


The Speculator’s Edge, Seven


The Important Role of the Speculator

In the previous instalments we learned that the subjective valuations of consumers ultimately dictate how society’s scarce productive resources will be allocated. If the markets were comprised of only producers and consumers, the process would be very inefficient. Consumers are concerned with their needs today. They purchase the food, clothing, and other goods they want today. They are rarely concerned with next year’s desires, and when they are, they are probably acting in a speculative capacity (which, of course, all of us are free to do). By looking to the future, speculators assure that society’s productive resources will be allocated not only according to the current preferences of consumers, but also taking into account their probable needs for tomorrow.

The objective of speculators is to profit from anticipated changes in conditions. Unlike those who purchase for consumption, speculators purchase in anticipation of being able to sell later at a higher price, and they sell in anticipation of buying in at a lower price. Accordingly, the valuation process of speculators differs significantly in character from that of consumers. Consumers are interested only in the current utility of a good to them. Speculators purchase not for their own consumption and not based on current utility alone. Instead, speculators are interested in what they assess the utility of a good to consumers will be in the future.

If conditions were static, the market would cause goods and services to be produced and distributed such that no further action by any individual would be perceived to be advantageous. Sellers would sell all that they were willing to sell at the prevailing price. Buyers would buy all that they were willing to buy. Prices would reach equilibrium and then become final. Trade would cease. Society’s utility would be maximized. There would be no reason to speculate, no benefit that speculation might confer on the economy.

But conditions change continually and the needs, valuations, and means of consumers change as well. And it is here that the speculator enters the picture. While it is the preference of consumers that ultimately determines the price of a good, it is the activity of speculators that pushes the market forward. The action of speculators as a class does not cause prices to reflect current utility, but instead moves prices to reflect future utility. As prices are determined in the markets there can be no distinction between the demand of consumers and that of speculators. That is, the speculators compete with consumers based on the speculators’ assessment of the consumers future needs. To succeed, speculators must have a keener ability to adjust to changing conditions than producers or consumers.

The Speculator’s Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli

Friday, November 23, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Six

The Speculator’s Edge, Six


Basic Economic Concepts essential to Speculation

7) How Consumers Direct Production through the Market

The ultimate arbiter of price is the consumer. As we have seen, the consumer’s valuation is based upon his or her subjective appraisal of the utility of a good. If the consumer needs something and can make an advantageous trade, he or she does so. If the price is too high, he or she will not pay it. Good business people know that they cannot stay in business for very long by producing what they wish to sell – they must produce what their customers wish to buy.

The market directs the individuals that comprise it. It tells producers what and how much to produce, and where, how, and when to deliver it. It also determines which of the consumers who desire goods will obtain them. It does this through the mechanism of price.

If consumers want more of something than is currently being produced, producers recognize the increased demand and raise their prices. The increased prices serve two functions. The most immediate impact is to ration the existing supply by providing the goods only to those consumers willing to pay the increased price. Marginal consumers, the ones that were not willing to buy at the lower (but not the higher) price, are precluded from buying. Equally important, but usually slower to occur, the higher prices encourage (1) more production of goods for which demand has increased and (2) reduced production of marginal goods of a different nature.

Supply and demand meet each other in many different locations and under many different rules. They meet in your grocery store. They meet on exchanges and in boardrooms. They meet on street corners too.

Producers supply the goods that consumers demand.

They can do it inefficiently at the direction of a centralized government as is common in some socialist and communist countries. Or they can do it efficiently, as directed by speculators in a free economy. The next instalment of this series will go on to show how speculators direct the markets to maximize the utility of society as a whole.

The Speculator’s Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli















Thursday, November 22, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Five


The Speculator’s Edge, Five


Basic Economic Concepts essential to Speculation

5) The Law of Market Equilibrium

The law of market equilibrium states that markets tend to equilibrium, a state in which neither the buyers nor the sellers see any need to change the price or quantity of the goods they are trading. This occurs at the price at which goods clear – that is, where producers sell as much as they are willing and able to sell and consumers buy as much as they are willing and able to buy, and further trading ceases.

How and why the law of equilibrium works may be easily seen if we combine our supply-and-demand schedules as follows:

                    Quantity          Quantity
Price            Demanded       Supplied       Effect on Price Structure
$1.50/lb        500 lbs             6000 lbs        Sellers will compete to fill limited demand,
                                                                    lowering prices
$1.00/lb       1000 lbs            5000 lbs         Sellers will compete to fill limited demand,
                                                                    lowering prices
$.50/lb          2500 lbs           2500 lbs         Equilibrium price occurs and trade is
                                                                     maximized
$.25/lb          5000 lbs           1000 lbs         Buyers will compete for limited supply,
                                                                     raising prices
$.10/lb          6000 lbs             200 lbs         Buyers will compete for limited supply,
                                                                     raising prices

Note that the equilibrium price in the above example is $.50 per pound of cotton, and, at that price, the maximum trade of 2500 pounds will take place. Assuming static conditions, once this 2500 pounds of cotton has been exchanged, no further trade will occur.

If the price were higher than the equilibrium price, producers would compete with each other for the relatively limited demand of consumers. Producers compete by lower price. The price would fall to equilibrium. (Surplus conditions)

If the prices were under the equilibrium price, consumers would bid prices up (or producers would simply raise them to ration goods) until demand and supply came into line at equilibrium. (Shortage conditions)

At equilibrium, there is neither a shortage nor a surplus. Here, producers sell all that they are willing to sell and consumers buy all that they are willing to buy. When distribution is complete, the market is said to “clear” and further trading ceases.

You might be thinking, why doesn’t the market ever seem to go to equilibrium and clear in the real world?

Although there is some academic debate on the extent to which equilibrium is ever achieved, at least one important school says that the market in fact is always at equilibrium. Even in highly organized, actively traded markets like those found on U.S. securities and commodities exchanges, trading ceases frequently – sometimes for an instant and sometimes for significant periods. Ultimately, however, conditions change. People’s needs change. They eat, then grow hungry all over again. They are born and they die. Their valuations change. A price that a moment ago was too high for a potential buyer now looks good, so he or she buys. As life goes on, the price structure of goods must fluctuate.

6) Shifts in Demand and Supply

If for some reason, demand for cotton increased under conditions of static supply, the equilibrium price of cotton would shift (rise) from $.50 per pound to $.75 per pound.
Of course, the supply for cotton could shift as well. If the supply for cotton dramatically increased, the producers, whose cost of production has been suddenly reduced would be willing to sell more cotton at reduced prices. The increase in supply under static demand would cause the equilibrium price to fall from $.50 per pound to $.35 per pound.

The Speculator’s Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli







Wednesday, November 21, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Four


The Speculator’s Edge, Four


Basic Economic Concepts essential to Speculation

4) The Laws of Downward-Sloping Demand and Upward-Sloping Supply

Demand is the quantity of a good that buyers are willing and able to purchase at a given price.

Supply is the quantity of a good that sellers are willing and able to sell at a given price.

The law of downward- sloping demand says that, ceteris paribus (all things being equal), demand is inversely related to price. The law of upward-sloping supply says that, ceteris paribus, supply is directly related to price. In other words, in a free market, where the non-price determinants remain the same:
  
as price increases, demand decreases
as price increases, supply increases
as price decreases, demand increases
as price decreases, supply decrease

These relationships are often depicted in demand and supply schedules and charts. A demand schedule shows the relationship between the quantity of a good demanded and the price charged. The demand schedule includes not only the amount actually demanded at the current prevailing price, but also the amount purchasers would be willing to buy at different prices.

Price……………………..Quantity Demanded
$1.50/lb………………….500 lbs
$1.00/lb………………….1000 lbs
$.50/lb………………...…2500 lbs
$.25/lb…………………...5000 lbs
$.10/lb…………………...6000 lbs

Similarly, supply schedules show the relationship between price and the amount of a good that sellers are willing to sell.

Price……………………..Quantity Supplied
$1.50/lb………………….6000 lbs
$1.00/lb………………….5000 lbs
$.50/lb………………...…2500 lbs
$.25/lb…………………...1000 lbs
$.10/lb…………………...200 lbs

The laws of upward-sloping supply and downward-sloping of demand follow our common sense. In general, if the price of a good is high, we will buy less of it than if it is lower. By lowering prices, producers can frequently entice new purchasers to buy and existing purchasers to buy more.

It is extremely important to note that while demand is inversely related to price, the relationship is not necessarily one to one. Let’s take an example. A luxury car costs, perhaps $120,000. I do not own a luxury car. If they cut the price to $60,000, I would buy one. If they cut the price to $30,000, I might not buy a second, because its marginal utility to me is less than $30,000. But if they reduce the price to $1, I might want to buy seven of them.

The law of supply operates in the same fashion. If there is plenty of something around, we are unwilling to sacrifice much to get it. As the supply becomes scarce, what we are willing to pay will increase as well, though, again, not necessarily on a one-for-one basis.

There is another way of saying all this that you should consider. Everything else being equal, if producers decide to increase the quantity of goods sold, they can do so only by decreasing the price at which they offer their goods.

The Speculator’s Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli







Tuesday, November 20, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Three


The Speculator’s Edge, Three


Basic Economic Concepts essential to Speculation

3) Money and Price
  
Now suppose Fred takes a box of burgers over to Murray, the roof repairman. As it turns out, Murray has just returned from the doctor, who told him to cut down on cholesterol. This puts Fred in a spot because, while Murray has something Fred wants, Fred doesn’t have anything Murray wants. Or does he? It turns out that Murray is a sportsman who likes to hunt on weekends for fun. Murray sees Fred’s new club and says he would gladly re-roof Fred’s hut in exchange for one just like it. So back Fred goes to Barney’s, where he trades the box of burgers for another club. Then he returns to Murray’s and makes the deal.

Something important has happened here. Instead of purchasing the second club for his own consumption, Fred traded first with Barney for the purpose of entering into a second transaction with Murray. In other words, Fred’s demand for the second club reflected nothing more than its exchange value to him. Its consumption value was important only to Murray. This is called an indirect exchange. Virtually all exchanges made in advanced society are of this nature.

Fred, Barney, and Murray now have a problem. Obviously, clubs and brontosaurus burgers are not particularly useful media of exchange. What is needed is something easier to carry, more durable, with generally recognized beauty or utility. Nails, gems, copper, nickel, silver and gold are all candidates, and, in fact, have been used by one society or another. One by one the alternatives get whittled down, usually not by any formalized decision process, but by custom and usage. Today the most universally recognized medium of exchange (excluding for the moment bank notes of the U.S. Federal Reserve and other currencies) is gold.

We are now in a position to define money…In the narrowest sense; money is a commodity that is universally employed as a medium of exchange. I say in the narrowest sense, because as we have become more sophisticated we have often replaced commodity money with other forms of money that have no underlying commodity value. Like dollar bills or the bits and bites in a computer and/or cyberspace that represent dollar bills.
 
It is astonishing that, for all the fuss we make about money, so few of us understand its nature or from whence its value derives. Money originated as commodity money. Initially, it had no value other than its consumption or production value. However, as its usefulness in facilitating indirect exchanges grew, its value also grew to a premium over its commodity value. It acquired money value. Unlike other goods, the value of money as money depends solely on its usefulness in facilitating exchange. Take away its exchange value, and the value of commodity money reverts back to its commodity value. From 1873 until the early 1930s, the value of silver declined as most countries demonetized it in favour of gold. During World War I, as many countries replaced gold with bank notes and Treasury notes, the value of gold declined as well.

The almighty dollar is the ultimate expression of the evolution from commodity money to what we call fiat money. Not long ago it was backed by silver – that is, the paper money could be exchanged for (substituted) for a given quantity of silver, a commodity that had both commodity value and money value. Once liberated from its precious metal backing, the dollar became nothing more than paper money – that is, its commodity value disappeared. The dollar is called fiat money because it is created out of paper by fiat of the United States government. Its current value is based on custom and belief only. If anything happened to destroy that belief, its value would revert to its consumption value only – that is, it would be worth the paper it is printed on, nothing more. 

Now that we know what money is, let’s return to our friends, Fred and company, to find out a little more about price and utility.

Let’s suppose Fred had five pieces of gold. Let’s suppose that Fred knew Barney would give him a club for ten pieces of gold and that Murray, who decided not to follow his doctor’s orders, would exchange five pieces of gold for a box of brontosaurus burgers. Obviously, Fred’s best course of action is to sell the burgers to Murray and then take the ten pieces of gold to Barney’s and buy a new club. We could say that one club cost two boxes of burgers, and indeed it did. We also could say that one club cost ten pieces of gold (or ten dollars if dollars happen to be the common medium of exchange), and we usually do. In other words, the price of a good can be expressed in terms of any other good for which it can be exchanged, or it can be expressed in terms of money. Remember, money is a commodity in most respects like any other commodity.

Now, is one club really worth two boxes of burgers simply because Barney said so?...Of course not.

Remember, it takes two to make a trade. A trade takes place when and only when there is disagreement on the utility of the goods exchanged. In fact, there is no such thing as fair value or true value in an economic sense. The market is nothing more than a series of trades among individuals who disagree as to the utility of the goods or services traded.

You now know all you need to know about what prices are and how they reflect the basic needs of the individuals who come to the markets. But what causes prices to be one thing and not another? What can we say about how objective prices are discovered?

Stay tuned…

The Speculator’s Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli


Monday, November 19, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge, Two


The Speculator’s Edge, Two


Basic Economic Concepts essential to Speculation

2) Utility
  
Let’s see how these characteristics take effect in the real world.

Consider the case of Fred, a hunter. His basic economic needs include shelter, clothes, tools with which to hunt, and food. Since his society has achieved division of labour. Fred doesn’t expect to make his hut, clothes, or clubs; his job is to hunt. He is sufficiently proficient at it to kill more than he can eat. If he weren’t, he would have to find another job.

One afternoon, after a particularly tasty brontosaurus burger, Fred looks about and notices that his tiger-skin loincloth is going out of style, his club is splintering and needs to be replaced, and the roof on his hut is leaking. He goes over to the refrigerator and sees that he has stored up several boxes of brontosaurus burgers from his last hunting trip. He knows that Barney, the club maker, loves brontosaurus burgers, so Fred figures that Barney will be willing to trade a new club for a box of burgers. Since Fred needs a new club and since he can always get more burgers once he acquires one, he decides to make a trade on this basis. So he goes over to Barney’s and trades the burgers for the club.

This primitive trade is called a direct exchange. The important thing about it is that it takes place only because the utility of a new club is greater to Fred than a box of brontosaurus burgers, and the reverse is true for Barney. We can describe the trade as having taken place at a price: The Price of one club was one box of brontosaurus burgers. Note that while the price can be specifically described, the trade took place not because Fred and Barney agreed on the utility of the goods exchanged, but because they disagreed! If both Fred and Barney valued a club more than burgers, then no trade would have taken place.

Consider Fred’s position immediately before he goes over to Barney’s to buy a new club. Fred must engage in a little self-examination. Since his needs are many and his resources are scarce, he has to decide what his priorities are before he goes on a shopping spree. His decision is as follows:

1) a new club
2) a new roof
3) a new loincloth
4) a box of brontosaurus burgers
5) another box of brontosaurus burgers
6) another club
7) another loincloth

This list of priorities is based on the utility of the goods on the list. Since Fred just ate, the brontosaurus burgers are relatively far down the list. What Fred needs most right now is a new club so he can go hunting and obtain food to eat and to trade. The roof is next in importance, because Fred prefers to sleep in a dry hut. Next in importance is a new loincloth since the one he’s wearing is in tatters. Then comes a couple of boxes of brontosaurus burgers, which occupy their lower spot because Fred already has several  boxes in the refrigerator and he has just eaten.

Note that the additional club and loincloth are at the bottom of the list, since they are not needed as much as the identical items at the top of the list. This is an important point. While extra clubs and loincloths benefit Fred, the incremental benefit of each additional club or loincloth becomes smaller. Economists describe this phenomenon in an important law – the law of diminishing marginal utility. Simply stated, the law of diminishing marginal utility says that as the amount of a good consumed increases, the marginal utility of that good tends to decrease. So, economists like to say that the marginal utility of a second club is less for Fred than the other items above it on the list.

Of course, the list itself is a list of Fred’s subjective values. But Fred lives in an objective world. That is, the items on Fred’s list are also on other people’s lists, but not necessarily in the same order. For example, people who can’t hunt to save their lives have little desire for clubs at all, except to the extent that they can trade them for other goods that they do want. People who had their huts re-roofed just last week wouldn’t trade a berry for a new one this week. As all these people come to the market, they make trades that make sense to them subjectively, and just as important, they refuse to make trades that do not make sense. In other words, people allocate their own limited resources in such a way as to maximize their own subjective utility – they keep making trades until their schedule of assets conforms to their list of priorities. In the aggregate, the subjective needs of all of the participants in the market result in an objective hierarchy of goods. At any given moment, the prevailing hierarchy, regardless of what you or I think of it, is the hierarchy of objective values.

The Speculator's Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli












Sunday, November 18, 2018

The Speculator’s Edge


The Speculator’s Edge

The next few blog posts has to do with a generic way to approach the markets in general. The material is from a terrific book published back in 1989 by Albert Peter Pacelli called the Speculator's Edge. The book mostly pertains to the Futures market but has applications for any market..


Basic Economic Concepts essential to Speculation

1) The Economics of Scarcity

Let’s begin with a few simple observations. First of all, our world is, in some respects, imperfect. Specifically, we live in a world of scarcity – one in which unlimited supplies of everything are not accessible to everyone.

Our second observation is that we live in a society, in which labor is divided. This is so obvious the alternative seems impossible to us, but it is probable that for most of human history, man produced exclusively to meet his own needs (i.e, Fred not only hunted, but made the club he hunted with, the tiger-skin loincloth he wore while hunting, etc.). Human beings who produce goods for the consumption of others will behave in a manner different from those who produce solely for their own consumption. For one thing, these humans will trade.

A society with scarce goods and divided labor has several problems. It must decide what will be produced, who will produce it and how, and who will receive it. Various systems have been tried. The one our society selected is called a market economy.

In our society, private ownership of property is permitted and the means of production and distribution of goods are, at least in major part, left up to individuals. This is what we mean when we say that ours is a free market system. Our system stands in sharp contrast to others in which production and distribution are directed by the state.

The Speculator's Edge,
Albert Peter Pacelli